Christopher Makler
Stanford University Department of Economics
Econ 50: Lecture 21
Friday Class:
Brooke Jenkins
SF District Attorney
Bishop Auditorium
5 participation points!!
What, as a society, do we produce?
Who gets what?
How do we decide?
If you were an omniscient
"social planner" in charge of everything, how would you
make these decisions?
How do billions of people
coordinate their economic activities?
What does it mean to
"let the market decide"
what to produce?
Firms face prices and
choose how much to produce
Consumers face prices and
choose how much to buy
Consumers and producers are small relative to the market
(like an individual firefly)
and make one decision: how much to buy or sell at the market price.
Equilibrium occurs when
the market price is such that
the total quantity demanded
equals the total quantity supplied
Definition 1: a situation which economic forces are "balanced"
Definition 2: a situation which is
self-replicating: \(x = f(x)\)
Transition dynamics: excess demand and supply
All forces can be in balance in different ways.
Perfect information
Homogeneous good
Lots of buyers and sellers
Free entry and exit
Individual demand curve, \(d^i(p)\): quantity demanded by consumer \(i\) at each possible price
Market demand sums across all consumers:
If all of those consumers are identical and demand the same amount \(d(p)\):
There are \(N_C\) consumers, indexed with superscript \(i \in \{1, 2, 3, ..., N_C\}\).
Market demand curve, \(D(p)\): quantity demanded by all consumers at each possible price
Firm supply curve, \(s^j(p)\): quantity supplied by firm \(j\) at each possible price
Market supply sums across all firms:
If all of those firms are identical and supply the same amount \(s(p)\):
There are \(N_F\) competitive firms, indexed with superscript \(j \in \{1, 2, 3, ..., N_F\}\).
Market supply curve, \(S(p)\): quantity supplied by all firms at each possible price
Price \(p^*\) is an equilibrium price in a market if:
1. Consumer Optimization: each consumer \(i\) is consuming a quantity \(x_i^*(p^*)\) that solves their utility maximization problem.
2. Firm Optimization: each firm \(j\) is producing a quantity \(q_j^*(p^*)\) that solves their profit maximization problem.
3. Market Clearing: the total quantity demanded by all consumers equals the total quantity supplied by all firms.
"Marginal benefit in dollars per unit of good 1"
\(N_C\) identical consumers, each of whom
has the Cobb-Douglas utility function
\(N_F\) identical firms produce good 1, each of which
has the Cobb-Douglas production function
Week 5: Demand for Good 1
Week 8: Supply of Good 1
and income \(m\)
and capital fixed in the short run at \(\overline K\)
1. Solve for the equilibrium price and quantity if \(\alpha = \frac{1}{4}, m = 100, N_C = 64, w = 4, \overline K = 2, N_F = 16\)
2. Solve for general formula for the equilibrium price and quantity.
pollev.com/chrismakler
Suppose that instead of 16 firms, we had only 9 firms.
Then, we would expect the equilibrium price to _____ and the equilibrium quantity to _____.
(Hint: think about what happens to the market demand and supply curves.)
1. Mathematical Identity: holds by definition
2. Optimization condition: holds when an agent is optimizing
3. Equilibrium condition: holds when a system is in equilibrium
Two consumers:
Consumer Optimization: Each consumer sets MRS = price ratio
Market Demand: Sum up individual demands for all people:
This leads to the individual demand functions:
Market Demand: Sum up individual demands for all people:
pollev.com/chrismakler
Suppose that Adam's preferences were instead given by
\(u^A(x_1,x_2) = 16 \ln x_1 + x_2\)
If Eve's preferences were still
\(u^E(x_1,x_2) = 4 \ln x_1 + x_2\)
what would the market demand be?
Two firms: Subway's has \(\overline K = 2\), Togo's has \(\overline K =1\), both pay wage rate \(w = 4\).
Firm Optimization: Each firm sets P = MC
Market Supply: Sum up individual supply for all firms:
Solving for \(q_S\) and \(q_T\) gives us the firms' individual supply functions:
Market Supply: Sum up individual supply for all firms:
Let's bring our consumers and firms together!
1. Consumer Optimization: each consumer \(i\) is consuming a quantity \(x_i^*(p^*)\) that solves their utility maximization problem.
2. Firm Optimization: each firm \(j\) is producing a quantity \(q_j^*(p^*)\) that solves their profit maximization problem.
3. Market Clearing: the total quantity demanded by all consumers equals the total quantity supplied by all firms.
Note: if we go back to the individual demand
and supply functions, we get:
If consumers pay the tax:
If firms pay the tax:
If they split it evenly:
Imposing a Tax
Equilibrium price and quantity with no tax.
Equilibrium quantity and prices
faced by consumers and firms if
consumers pay a tax of t = 10.
Equilibrium quantity and prices
faced by consumers and firms if
firms pay a tax of t = 10.
Tax burden for consumers:
the amount of the tax that results in an increase in the price paid by consumers,
relative to the equilibrium price
Tax burden for firms:
the amount of the tax that results in an decrease in the price received by firms,
relative to the equilibrium price
What is the burden in this case?
How does tax burden relate to the relative elasticities of demand and supply?
The equilibrium quantity, price paid by consumers, and price received by firms doesn't depend on who pays the tax
It does depend on the relative elasticity of demand and supply.
Doing the math on elasticity
Previously: agents took the price
"as given" (exogenous) - it was determined outside the model
Today: we endogenized
the market price by analyzing the model where it's determined
Next time: is the market price "good"?