Christopher Makler
Stanford University Department of Economics
Econ 50
Far out in the uncharted backwaters of the unfashionable end of the western spiral arm of the Galaxy lies a small unregarded yellow sun.
SCIEPRO/GETTY IMAGES
Orbiting this at a distance of roughly ninety-two million miles is an utterly insignificant little blue green planet whose ape-descended life forms are so amazingly primitive that they still think digital watches are a pretty neat idea.
This planet has — or rather had —
a problem, which was this:
😢
most of the people on it were unhappy for pretty much of the time.
Many solutions were proposed
for this problem...
...but most of these were largely concerned with the movements
of small green pieces of paper,
which is odd because on the whole
it wasn't the small green pieces of paper that were unhappy.
Resources
Technology
Stuff
Happiness
🌎
🏭
⌚️
🤓
Demand
Supply
Equilibrium
🤩
🏪
⚖
Optimization
Given a fixed set of circumstances (prices, technology, preferences), how do economic agents (consumers, firms) make choices?
Comparative Statics
How do changes in circumstances (changing prices, shifting technology, preferences, etc.) translate into changes in behavior?
Equilibrium
How do economic systems converge toward certain outcomes?
Economics is the study of how
we use scarce resources
to satisfy our unlimited wants
Resources
Goods
Happiness
🌎
⌚️
🤓
Labor
Fish
🐟
Capital
Coconuts
🥥
[GOODS]
⏳
⛏
[RESOURCES]
Economics is the study of how
we use scarce resources
to satisfy our unlimited wants
Resources
Goods
Happiness
🌎
⌚️
🤓
🐟
🥥
Production Possibilities Fronier
Feasible
Economics is the study of how
we use scarce resources
to satisfy our unlimited wants
Resources
Goods
Happiness
🌎
⌚️
🤓
🐟
🥥
🙂
😀
😁
😢
🙁
Economics is the study of how
we use scarce resources
to satisfy our unlimited wants
Resources
Goods
Happiness
🌎
⌚️
🤓
🐟
🥥
Optimal choice
🙂
😀
😁
😢
🙁
Economics is the study of how
we use scarce resources
to satisfy our unlimited wants
Resources
Goods
Happiness
🌎
⌚️
🤓
Take total derivative of both sides with respect to x:
Solve for dy/dx:
IMPLICIT FUNCTION THEOREM
Labor (L)
Capital (K)
Production Function f(L,K)
Output (q or x)
Isoquant: combinations of inputs that produce a given level of output
Isoquant map: a contour map showing the isoquants for various levels of output
(absolute value)
Christopher Makler
Stanford University Department of Economics
Econ 50: Lecture 4
Two "Goods" (e.g. fish and coconuts)
A bundle is some quantity of each good
Can plot this in a graph with x1 on the horizontal axis and x2 on the vertical axis
What tradeoff is represented by moving
from bundle A to bundle B?
ANY SLOPE IN
GOOD 1 - GOOD 2 SPACE
IS MEASURED IN
UNITS OF GOOD 2
PER UNIT OF GOOD 1
ANY SLOPE IN
GOOD 1 - GOOD 2 SPACE
IS MEASURED IN
UNITS OF GOOD 2
PER UNIT OF GOOD 1
TW: HORRIBLE STROBE EFFECT!
Labor
Fish
🐟
Coconuts
🥥
[GOOD 1]
⏳
[GOOD 2]
Fish production function
Coconut production function
Resource Constraint
Fish production function
Coconut production function
Resource Constraint
Suppose we're allocating 100 units of labor to fish (good 1),
and 50 of labor to coconuts (good 2).
Now suppose we shift
one unit of labor
from coconuts to fish.
How many fish do we gain?
100
98
300
303
How many coconuts do we lose?
Fish production function
Coconut production function
Resource Constraint
PPF
Christopher Makler
Stanford University Department of Economics
Econ 50: Lecture 5
Given a choice between option A and option B, an agent might have different preferences:
The agent strictly prefers A to B.
The agent strictly disprefers A to B.
The agent weakly prefers A to B.
The agent weakly disprefers A to B.
The agent is indifferent between A and B.
Visually: the MRS is the magnitude of the slope
of an indifference curve
How do we model preferences mathematically?
Approach: assume consuming goods "produces" utility
Labor
Fish
🐟
Capital
⏳
⛏
[RESOURCES]
Utility
😀
[GOODS]
Fish
🐟
Coconuts
🥥
"A is strictly preferred to B"
Words
Preferences
Utility
"A is weakly preferred to B"
"A is indifferent to B"
"A is weakly dispreferred to B"
"A is strictly dispreferred to B"
Suppose the "utility function"
assigns a real number (in "utils")
to every possible consumption bundle
We get completeness because any two numbers can be compared,
and we get transitivity because that's a property of the operator ">"
Given a utility function u(x1,x2),
we can interpret the partial derivatives
as the "marginal utility" from
another unit of either good:
Along an indifference curve, all bundles will produce the same amount of utility
In other words, each indifference curve
is a level set of the utility function.
The slope of an indifference curve is the MRS. By the implicit function theorem,
(Note: we'll treat this as a positive number, just like the MRTS and the MRT)
Applying a positive monotonic transformation to a utility function doesn't affect
its MRS at any bundle (and therefore generates the same indifference map).
Example: u^(x1,x2)=ln(u(x1,x2))
We've asserted that all (rational) preferences are complete and transitive.
There are some additional properties which are true of some preferences:
Take any two bundles, A and B, between which you are indifferent.
Would you rather have a convex combination of those two bundles,
than have either of those bundles themselves?
If you would always answer yes, your preferences are convex.
Take any two bundles, A and B, between which you are indifferent.
Would you rather have a convex combination of those two bundles,
than have either of those bundles themselves?
If you would always answer no, your preferences are convex.
Red pencils and blue pencils, if you con't care about color
One-dollar bills and five-dollar bills
One-liter bottles of soda and two-liter bottles of soda
Charlotte always has 2 biscuits with every cup of tea;
if she has a plate of biscuits and one cup of tea, she'll only eat two. (And if she has a whole pot of tea and 6 biscuits, she'll stop pouring after 3 cups of tea.)
Each (cup + 2 biscuits) gives her 10 utils of joy.
Which other bundles give her the same utility as
3 cups of tea and 4 biscuits (A)?
Which other bundles give her the same utility as
1 cup of tea and 4 biscuits (B)?
3
6
Any combination that has 4 biscuits
and 2 or more cups of tea
Any combination that has 1 cup of tea and
at 2 or more biscuits
4
5
1
2
3
6
4
5
1
2
A
B
Left shoes and right shoes
Sugar and tea
Used for two independent goods (neither complements nor substitutes) -- e.g., t-shirts vs hamburgers
Also called "constant shares" for reasons we'll see later.
Marginal utility of good 2 is constant
If good 2 is "dollars spent on other things," utility from good 1 is often given as if it were in dollars.
Choice space:
all possible options
Feasible set:
all options available to you
Optimal choice:
Your best choice(s) of the ones available to you
Suppose g(x1,x2) is monotonic (increasing in both x1 and x2).
Then k−g(x1,x2) is negative if you're outside of the constraint,
positive if you're inside the constraint,
and zero if you're along the constraint.
OBJECTIVE
FUNCTION
CONSTRAINT
FIRST ORDER CONDITIONS
3 equations, 3 unknowns
Solve for x1, x2, and λ
The story so far, in two graphs
Production Possibilities Frontier
Resources, Production Functions → Stuff
Indifference Curves
Stuff → Happiness (utility)
Both of these graphs are in the same "Good 1 - Good 2" space
Better to produce
more good 1
and less good 2.
Better to produce
less good 1
and more good 2.
Better to produce
more good 1
and less good 2.
Better to produce
more good 2
and less good 1.
These forces are always true.
In certain circumstances, optimality occurs where MRS = MRT.
We've just seen that, at least under certain circumstances, the optimal bundle is
"the point along the PPF where MRS = MRT."
CONDITION 1:
CONSTRAINT CONDITION
CONDITION 2:
TANGENCY
CONDITION
This is just an application of the Lagrange method!
Chuck has 150 hours of labor, and can produce 3 coconuts per hour or 2 fish per hour.
His preferences may be represented by the utility function u(x1,x2)=x12x2
OBJECTIVE
FUNCTION
CONSTRAINT
FIRST ORDER CONDITIONS
Utility from last hour spent fishing
Utility from last hour spent collecting coconuts
Equation of PPF
Utility from last hour spent fishing
Utility from last hour spent collecting coconuts
Equation of PPF
Equation of PPF
TANGENCY
CONDITION
MRS
MRT
CONSTRAINT
Optimal bundle contains
strictly positive quantities of both goods
Optimal bundle contains zero of one good
(spend all resources on the other)
If only consume good 1: MRS≥MRT at optimum
If only consume good 2: MRS≤MRT at optimum
What would Lagrange find...?
Discontinuities in the MRS
(e.g. Perfect Complements utility function)
Discontinuities in the MRT
(e.g. homework question with two factories)
If preferences are nonmonotonic,
you might be satisfied consuming something within the interior of your feasible set.
FISH
COCONUTS
PPF
avoids a satiation point within the constraint
At the left corner of the constraint, MRS>MRT
avoids a corner solution when x1=0
Monotonicity (more is better)
At the right corner of the constraint, MRS<MRT
avoids a corner solution when x2=0
MRS and MRT are continuous as you move along the constraint
avoids a solution at a kink
ensures FOCs find a maximum, not a minimum
Convexity (variety is better)
Christopher Makler
Stanford University Department of Economics
Econ 50: Lecture 10
Resources
Technology
Stuff
Happiness
🏭
⌚️
🤓
⏳
⛏
Resources
Firms
Stuff
Consumers
⏳
🏭
⌚️
🤓
Resource
Owners
👷🏽♀️
⛏
🏦
Resources
Firms
Stuff
Consumers
⏳
🏭
⌚️
🤓
Resource
Owners
👷🏽♀️
⛏
🏦
💵
💵
💵
Firms pay wages for labor
Firms pay rent on capital
Consumers pay prices for goods
Demand
Supply
🤩
🏪
Suppose each good has a constant price
(so every unit of the good costs the same)
Suppose you have a given income m
to spend on goods 1 and 2.
Then bundle X=(x1,x2) is affordable if
Example: suppose you have m=$240 to spend on two goods.
Good 1 costs p1=$3 per unit.
Good 2 costs p2=$4 per unit.
Is the bundle (10,40) affordable (in your budget set)? What about the bundle (40,40)?
Draw your budget set.
How would it change if the price of good 1 rose to p1′=$6 per unit?
How would it change if your income dropped to m′=$120?
Example:
Apples cost 50 cents each
Bananas cost 25 cents each
Slope of the budget line represents the opportunity cost of consuming good 1, as dictated by market prices.
In other words: it is the amount of good 2 the market requires you to give up in order to get another unit of good 1.
You have $100 in your pocket.
You see a cart selling apples (good 1) for $2 per pound.
🍏
🍌
BL
"Gravitational pull" argument:
Indifference curve is
steeper than the budget line
Indifference curve is
flatter than the budget line
Moving to the right
along the budget line
would increase utility.
Moving to the left
along the budget line
would increase utility.
🍏
🍌
BL
Can sometimes use the tangency condition
MRS=p1/p2, sometimes you have to use logic.
🍏
🍌
BL1
We will be solving for the optimal bundle
as a function of income and prices:
The solutions to this problem will be called the demand functions. We have to think about how the optimal bundle will change when p1,p2,m change.
BL2
MRS and the Price Ratio: Cobb-Douglas
The budget line and indifference curves describe different things.
Indifference curves describe the "shape of the utility hill."
They do not change when prices or income change.
They do change when preferences change, but we usually assume preferences are fixed.
The budget line describes the boundary of affordable bundles;
we can think of it as a fence over the utility hill.
IF...
THEN...
The consumer's preferences are "well behaved"
-- smooth, strictly convex, and strictly monotonic
MRS=0 along the horizontal axis (x2=0)
The budget line is a simple straight line
The optimal consumption bundle will be characterized by two equations:
More generally: the optimal bundle may be found using the Lagrange method
MRS→∞ along the vertical axis (x1→0)
First Order Conditions
"Bang for your buck" condition: marginal utility from last dollar spent on every good must be the same!
What happens when the price of a good increases or decreases?
What happens when income decreases?
Christopher Makler
Stanford University Department of Economics
Econ 50: Lecture 11
🍏
🍌
BL1
We will be solving for the optimal bundle
as a function of income and prices:
The solutions to this problem will be called the demand functions. We have to think about how the optimal bundle will change when p1,p2,m change.
BL2
Plug tangency condition back into constraint:
Tangency Condition: MRS=p1/p2
OPTIMAL BUNDLE
DEMAND FUNCTIONS
(optimization)
(comparative statics)
DEMAND CURVE FOR GOOD 1
"Good 1 - Good 2 Space"
"Quantity-Price Space for Good 1"
Remember what you learned about demand and demand curves in Econ 1 / high school:
...its own price changes?
Movement along the demand curve
...the price of another good changes?
Complements
Substitutes
Independent Goods
How does the quantity demanded of a good change when...
...income changes?
Normal goods
Inferior goods
Giffen goods
(possible) shift of the demand curve
...its own price changes?
Movement along the demand curve
How does the quantity demanded of a good change when...
The demand curve for a good
shows the quantity demanded of that good
as a function of its own price
holding all other factors constant
(ceteris paribus)
The price offer curve shows how the optimal bundle changes in good 1-good 2 space as the price of one good changes.
DEMAND CURVE FOR GOOD 1
"Good 1 - Good 2 Space"
"Quantity-Price Space for Good 1"
PRICE OFFER CURVE
...the price of another good changes?
How does the quantity demanded of a good change when...
When the price of one good goes up, demand for the other increases.
When the price of one good goes up, demand for the other decreases.
Demand not related
Complements: p2↑⇒x1∗↓
What happens to the quantity of good 1 demanded when the price of good 2 increases?
Substitutes: p2↑⇒x1∗↑
COMPLEMENTS:
UPWARD-SLOPING
PRICE OFFER CURVE
SUBSTITUTES:
DOWNWARD-SLOPING
PRICE OFFER CURVE
How does the quantity demanded of a good change when...
...income changes?
When your income goes up,
demand for the good increases.
When your income goes up,
demand for the good decreases.
The income offer curve shows how the optimal bundle changes in good 1-good 2 space as income changes.
Good 1 normal: m↑⇒x1∗↑
What happens to the quantity of good 1 demanded when the income increases?
Good 1 inferior: m↑⇒x1∗↓
BOTH NORMAL GOODS:
UPWARD-SLOPING
INCOME OFFER CURVE
ONE GOOD INFERIOR:
DOWNWARD-SLOPING
PRICE OFFER CURVE
PERFECT
SUBSTITUTES
PERFECT
COMPLEMENTS
INDEPENDENT
PERFECT
SUBSTITUTES
COMPLEMENTS: r<0
SUBSTITUTES: r>0
Christopher Makler
Stanford University Department of Economics
Econ 50: Lecture 13
Effect of change in relative prices, holding utility constant.
Effect of change in real income,
holding relative prices constant.
Suppose that, after a price change,
we compensated the consumer
just enough to afford some bundle
that would give the same utility
as they had before the price change?
The Hicks decomposition bundle
is the lowest-cost bundle
that satisfies this condition.
TOTAL EFFECT
INITIAL BUNDLE
FINAL BUNDLE
DECOMPOSITION BUNDLE
SUBSTITUTION EFFECT
INCOME EFFECT
TOTAL EFFECT
INITIAL BUNDLE
FINAL BUNDLE
DECOMPOSITION BUNDLE
SUBSTITUTION EFFECT
INCOME EFFECT
Movement along POC
Shift of IOC
Movement along IOC
Solution functions:
"Ordinary" Demand functions
Solution functions:
"Compensated" Demand functions
Plug tangency condition back into constraint:
Suppose the price of good 1 increases from p1 to p1′.
The price of good 2 (p2) and income (m) remain unchanged.
Initial Bundle (A):
Solves
utility maximization
problem
Final Bundle (C):
Solves
utility maximization
problem
Decomposition Bundle (B):
Solves
cost minimization
problem
"Compensated Budget Line"
The "compenated budget line" shows the budget line as if the consumer was given just enough money to achieve their initial utility at the new prices.
If a consumer's preferences are well behaved, her compensated budget line
When the price of good 1 goes up...
Net effect: buy less of both goods
Net effect: buy less good 1 and more good 2
Substitution effect: buy less of good 1 and more of good 2
Income effect (if both goods normal): buy less of both goods
Substitution effect dominates
Income effect dominates
Which of the following would be true if these goods were substitutes rather than complements?
pollev.com/chrismakler
Christopher Makler
Stanford University Department of Economics
Econ 50 : Lecture 15
Labor
Fish
🐟
Capital
Coconuts
🥥
[GOODS]
⏳
⛏
[RESOURCES]
Utility
🤓
The story thus far...
Labor
Fish
🐟
Capital
Coconuts
🥥
[GOODS]
⏳
⛏
[RESOURCES]
🤓
Consumer
The story thus far...
Labor
Firm
🏭
Capital
⏳
⛏
Customers
🤓
This unit: analyze the firms
consumers buy things from
Firm
🏭
Costs
Customers
🤓
This unit: analyze the firms
consumers buy things from
Firm
🏭
Costs
Revenue
From the firm's perspective, they get revenue and pay costs...
Costs
Revenue
Profit
Next week: Solve the optimization problem
finding the profit-maximizing quantity q∗
...which is what we call profits
Costs
Revenue
Profit
Today: Solve the cost minimization problem
and derive the cost function c(q)
Costs
Revenue
Profit
Today: Solve the cost minimization problem
and derive the cost function c(q)
Friday: Derive the revenue function r(q)
Costs
Revenue
Profit
Today: Solve the cost minimization problem
and derive the cost function c(q)
Friday: Derive the revenue function r(q)
Next Monday: Solve the profit maximization problem
Output Supply
Input Demands
Next Wednesday: Analyze the comparative statics
of how the optimal choice changes with prices
for the special case of a price-taking firm
Hicksian Demand
Conditional Demand
First Order Conditions
MRTS (slope of isoquant) is equal to the price ratio
A graph connecting the input combinations a firm would use as it expands production: i.e., the solution to the cost minimization problem for various levels of output
Exactly the same as the income offer curve (IOC) in consumer theory.
(And, if the optimum is found via a tangency condition, exactly the same as the tangency condition.)
Conditional demand for labor
Conditional demand for capital
"The total cost of producing q units in the long run
is the cost of the cost-minimizing combination of inputs
that can produce q units of output."
Exactly the same as the expenditure function in consumer theory.
If there's only one variable input,
it's perfectly inelastic -- there's only one choice!
Variable cost
"The total cost of producing q units in the short run is the variable cost of the required amount of the input that can be varied,
plus the fixed cost of the input that is fixed in the short run."
Fixed cost
Fixed Costs (F): All economic costs
that don't vary with output.
Variable Costs (VC(q)): All economic costs
that vary with output
explicit costs (rK) plus
implicit costs like opportunity costs
e.g. cost of labor required to produce
q units of output given K units of capital
Fixed Costs
Variable Costs
Average Fixed Costs (AFC)
Average Variable Costs (AVC)
Fixed Costs
Variable Costs
(marginal cost is the marginal variable cost)
Christopher Makler
Stanford University Department of Economics
Econ 50: Lecture 17
"X elasticity of Y"
or "Elasticity of Y with respect to X"
Examples:
"Price elasticity of demand"
"Income elasticity of demand"
"Cross-price elasticity of demand"
"Price elasticity of supply"
Perfectly Inelastic
Inelastic
Unit Elastic
Elastic
Perfectly Elastic
Doesn't change
Changes by less than the change in X
Changes proportionally to the change in X
Changes by more than the change in X
Changes "infinitely" (usually: to/from zero)
How does the endogenous variable Y respond to a
change in the exogenous variable X?
(note: all of these refer to the ratio of the perentage change, not absolute change)
Note: the slope of the relationship is b.
Elasticity is related to, but not the same thing as, slope.
This is related to logs, in a way that you can explore in the homework.
This is a super useful trick and one that comes up on midterms all the time!
The profit from q units of output
PROFIT
REVENUE
COST
is the revenue from selling them
minus the cost of producing them.
We will assume that the firm sells all units of the good for the same price, p. (No "price discrimination")
The revenue from q units of output
REVENUE
PRICE
QUANTITY
is the price at which each unit it sold
times the quantity (# of units sold).
The price the firm can charge may depend on the number of units it wants to sell: inverse demand p(q)
If the firm wants to sell q units, it sells all units at the same price p(q)
Since all units are sold for p, the average revenue per unit is just p.
By the product rule...
let's delve into this...
The total revenue is the price times quantity (area of the rectangle)
Note: MR<0 if
The total revenue is the price times quantity (area of the rectangle)
If the firm wants to sell dq more units, it needs to drop its price by dp
Revenue loss from lower price on existing sales of q: dp×q
Revenue gain from additional sales at p: dq×p
(multiply first term by p/p)
(simplify)
(since ϵ<0)
Notes
Elastic demand: MR>0
Inelastic demand: MR<0
In general: the more elastic demand is, the less one needs to lower ones price to sell more goods, so the closer MR is to p.
Christopher Makler
Stanford University Department of Economics
Econ 50: Lecture 18
Optimize by taking derivative and setting equal to zero:
Profit is total revenue minus total costs:
"Marginal revenue equals marginal cost"
Example:
What is the profit-maximizing value of q?
Multiply right-hand side by q/q:
Profit is total revenue minus total costs:
"Profit per unit times number of units"
AVERAGE PROFIT
Recall our elasticity representation of marginal revenue:
Let's combine it with this
profit maximization condition:
Really useful if MC and elasticity are both constant!
Inverse elasticity pricing rule:
Fraction of price that's markup over marginal cost
(Lerner Index)
What if ∣ϵ∣→∞?
(multiply first term by p/p)
(simplify)
(since ϵ<0)
Note
Perfectly elastic demand: MR=p
Price
MC
q
$/unit
P = MR
12
24
Christopher Makler
Stanford University Department of Economics
Econ 50 | Lecture 19
Exogenous Variables
Endogenous Variables
technology, f()
level of output, q
conditional
input demands
Cost Minimization
Isoquant
Isocost
lines
factor prices (w, r)
profit-maximizing output supply
Profit Maximization
output price, p
Total Revenue
Total Cost
profit-maximizing input demands
total cost
What is an agent's optimal behavior for a fixed set of circumstances?
Utility-maximizing bundle for a consumer
Profit-maximizing quantity for a firm
Profit-maximizing input choice for a firm
How does an agent's optimal behavior change when circumstances change?
Utility-maximizing bundle for a consumer
Profit-maximizing quantity for a firm
Profit-maximizing input choice for a firm
We will be analyzing a
competitive (price-taking) firm
TR
TC
MR
MC
Take derivative and set = 0:
Solve for q∗:
SUPPLY FUNCTION
1. Total costs = cost of required inputs
2. Profit = total revenues minus total costs
3. Take derivative of profit function, set =0
1. Total revenue = value of output produced
2. Profit = total revenues minus total costs
3. Take derivative of profit function, set =0
1. Total revenue = value of output produced
2. Profit = total revenues minus total costs
3. Take derivative of profit function, set =0
"Keep producing output as long as the marginal revenue from the last unit produced is at least as great as the marginal cost of producing it."
"Keep producing output as long as the marginal revenue from the last unit produced is at least as great as the marginal cost of producing it."
"Keep hiring workers as long as the marginal revenue from the output of the last worker is at least as great as the cost of hiring them."
TR
TC
MRPL
MC
Take derivative and set = 0:
Solve for L∗:
LABOR DEMAND FUNCTION
LABOR DEMAND FUNCTION
LABOR DEMAND FUNCTION
SUPPLY FUNCTION
the conditional labor demand
for the profit-maximizing supply:
The profit-maximizing labor demand is
Christopher Makler
Stanford University Department of Economics
Econ 50: Lectures 20 and 21
Firms face prices and
choose how much to produce
Consumers face prices and
choose how much to buy
Individual demand curve, di(p): quantity demanded by consumer i at each possible price
Market demand sums across all consumers:
If all of those consumers are identical and demand the same amount d(p):
There are NC consumers, indexed with superscript i∈{1,2,3,...,NC}.
Market demand curve, D(p): quantity demanded by all consumers at each possible price
Market demand sums across all consumers:
Firm supply curve, sj(p): quantity supplied by firm j at each possible price
Market supply sums across all firms:
If all of those firms are identical and supply the same amount s(p):
There are NF competitive firms, indexed with superscript j∈{1,2,3,...,NF}.
Market supply curve, S(p): quantity supplied by all firms at each possible price
Price p∗ is an equilibrium price in a market if:
1. Consumer Optimization: each consumer i is consuming a quantity xi∗(p∗) that solves their utility maximization problem.
2. Firm Optimization: each firm j is producing a quantity qj∗(p∗) that solves their profit maximization problem.
3. Market Clearing: the total quantity demanded by all consumers equals the total quantity supplied by all firms.
"Marginal benefit in dollars per unit of good 1"
1. Mathematical Identity: holds by definition
2. Optimization condition: holds when an agent is optimizing
3. Equilibrium condition: holds when a system is in equilibrium
If you were an omniscient social planner, could you do "better"
than the price the market "chooses"?
TOTAL WELFARE
(dollars)
Marginal welfare,
in dollars per unit:
Total benefit to consumers minus total cost to firms
Marginal benefit to consumers minus marginal cost to firms
Christopher Makler
Stanford University Department of Economics
Econ 50: Lecture 22
This Week:
General Equilibrium
Analyze a single market, taking everything determined outside that market as given
(prices of other goods,
consumer income, wages)
Last Week:
Partial Equilibrium
Today: examine linkages between markets
Analyze all markets simultaneously
Thursday: solve for equilibrium quantities in all markets simultaneously as a function only of production functions, resource constraints, and consumer preferences.
(endogenize all prices, income, wages)
Market for Good 2
Market for Good 1
Market for Good 2
Market for Good 1
Y1 = total amount of good 1 produced by all firms in an economy
Y2 = total amount of good 2 produced by all firms in an economy
GDP(Y1,Y2)=p1Y1+p2Y2
= market value of all final goods and services produced in an economy
Narrow question:
How many productive resources should we devote to a single good?
Broader question:
How should we allocate productive resources across goods?
Firms will choose the quantity at which p=MC
Firms will choose the point along the PPF at which p2p1=MRT
GDP maximizing point!!
Firms will choose the point along the PPF at which p2p1=MRT
How will they do this?
In this lecture, we'll show:
PROFIT MAX FOR GOOD 1
PROFIT MAX FOR GOOD 2
Input prices signal resource constraints, keep production on PPF.
TANGENCY CONDITION
CONSTRAINT CONDITION
Firms in industry 1 set p1=MC1
Firms in industry 2 set p2=MC2
How does competition achieve this?
Wages adjust until the
labor market clears
Consumers
Good 1 Firms
Market for Good 1
Market for Good 2
Market for Labor
Good 2 Firms
Money flows clockwise
Goods, labor flow counter-clockwise
General Equilibrium: Everyone optimizes, all markets clear simultaneously.
1. Given prices p1,p2, firms will choose the point (Y1∗,Y2∗) along the PPF where MRT=p2p1
2. All money received by firms (p1Y1∗+p2Y2∗) will become income M for consumers.
3. Given prices p1,p2 and income M, consumers will choose the point (X1∗,X2∗) along the budget line where MRS=p2p1
If consumers and firms all face the same price, and if they choose the same quantity in response to that price, then MRS = MRT.
In general equilibrium, everything having to do with money has been endogenized.
We are left with the same things Chuck had on his desert island:
resources, production technologies, and preferences.
As an individual in autarky, Chuck solved his maximization problem by setting
the marginal benefit of any activity he undertook equal to its opportunity cost.
Markets solve the problem of how to resolve scarcity in the same way:
by having everyone equate their own MB or MC to a common price,
which represents the opportunity cost of using resources in some other way.