Trading of Crypto-Assets
 

Instructor:           Andreas Park
 

 

Rotman – Master in Financial Risk Management

Financial Innovation

Background: Trading Crypto-Assets

  • This deck supplements my four part lecture series on Blockchain Technology in Finance
  • TWO parts
    • Trading in equity markets today
    • Trading in crypto-securities (including coins and tokens)
  • Please note: this presentation is under no circumstances to be taken as investment advice or encouragement to engage in activities that may violate current securities law.

Content Overview

Types of traders

Trading in Equity Markets today

Retail

Institutional

Pro-Traders

Exchanges

Wholesellers

Dark pools

Broker Internalizations

Where does trading occur?

Trading in Equity Markets today

Exchanges

Wholesellers

Dark pools

Broker Internalizations

How does trading work?

Trading in Equity Markets today

(

(

How to access the market?

Trading in Equity Markets today

Retail

Institutional

Pro-Traders

Retail: Canada

Trading in Equity Markets today

Rule: must send to exchange with best price 

Retail: U.S.A.

Trading in Equity Markets today

Exchange

Wholeseller

market order

limit order

In Europe: no best price obligation

Institutions: U.S.A.

Trading in Equity Markets today

Exchange

Dark pools

Pro Traders

Trading in Equity Markets today

Type 2: "borrow" broker-dealer system

Type 1: licenced broker-dealer

risk control

Big Message

Trading in Equity Markets today

  • You commonly don't access the market directly.

  • Brokers take many decisions but they are bound by regulations.

  • Critical: markets are formally linked by best-price rules.

A glimpse of overall infrastructure

Sue wants to sell ABX

Bob wants to buy ABX

sell order

buy order

Clearing House

Stock Exchange

Broker

Broker

3rd party tech

custodian

custodian

record beneficial ownership

central bank for payment

Three Fallacies for Crypto Economics

crypto assets = traditional equities

crypto trading = traditional trading

crypto entities = traditional firms

Case in point...

Types of traders

Trading in Crypto Markets

Retail, Institutions, and Pro-Traders are indistiguishable

not clear whether and which institutions are active 

Where does trading occur?

Trading in Crypto Markets

Exchanges

Dark pools

Smart On-chain contracts

Exchanges

Smart Contract

How does trading work?

Trading in Crypto Markets

Order Driven

Market Maker

How do you access the market?

Trading in Crypto Markets

Exchanges

Smart On-chain contracts

Within exchange operation

Trading in Crypto Markets

trade

lend

Settlement

Trading in Crypto Markets

trade

Fully decentralized 1.0

... 300 lines of code ...

Concerns

arbitrage is either not possible  or requires large capital commitment => expensive

exchanges = brokers? => single point of failure

decentralized: totally anonymous => easy price manipulation (e.g. wash trades)

Bitcoin prices in USD, May 25 2018, 17 exchanges

Arbitrage?

Pre-req for Trading on a Crypto Exchange

trade

Settle on the blockchain for digital "assets"

Wire transfer for fiat

Arbitrage on a Crypto Exchange

BTC/USD

ask: 7,600 

bid: 7,550

BTC/USD

ask: 7,500 

bid: 7,450

buy low 

sell high

Arbitrage on a Crypto Exchange

BTC/USD

ask: 7,600 

bid: 7,550

BTC/USD

ask: 7,500 

bid: 7,450

buy BTC

sell BTC

move BTC to Kraken

Arbitrage on a Crypto Exchange

Wire: free*; 1-5 days

Credit card: 3.5%

trading fee: 10-25 bps

flat fee in BTC \(\approx\) $4-8

\(\approx\) 10-60 minutes

trading fee: 0-26 bps

35 USD + 0.125%

($5 if >$50,000)

1-3 business days;

possible other fees/delays

Some exchanges allow short selling

What's the result?

Regulated Exchanges

Derivatives trade mostly offshore! Unregulated(?!)

Spirit of Blockchain: Fully decentralized

... 300 lines of code ...

standard trading rules practically impossible to enforce

Crypto exchanges are a security risk

August 2016

Crypto exchanges are a security risk

https://www.forbes.com/sites/jasonbrett/2019/12/19/congress-considers-federal-crypto-regulators-in-new-cryptocurrency-act-of-2020/#7ddcdfd65fcd

decentralized exchange

Key Components

Idea:

  • create a way to exchange items on-chain
  • fully decentralized
  • \(\to\) no single controlling entity, or location, everything runs with smart contracts

How should one organize DEX trading?

  • "DeFi refers to a fast-growing and highly opaque corner of the cryptocurrency market which allows users to engage in a variety of financial activities – including lending, borrowing, and trading derivatives to take on leverage – without an intermediary like a bank.
     
  • Given that participants and project developers may remain anonymous, DeFi could present particularly severe financial stability risks.
     
  • According to a 2019 Financial Stability Board report, decentralized financial technologies may raise new forms of concentration risks, unclear allocation of liability, and recovery and resolution challenges."

Source: Letter to Janet Yellen, Chair of the Financial Stability Oversight Council (FSOC) https://www.warren.senate.gov/imo/media/doc/FSOC%20Crypto%20Letter%2007.26.2021.pdf 

What is decentralized Finance and why should you care

“[…] the need for a coordinated and cohesive regulatory strategy to mitigate the growing risks that cryptocurrencies pose to the financial system”

How should one organize DEX trading?

How do you set the price?

  1. Use an oracle
  2. Use a hard-coded function

the constant product pricing function

automated market maker

Price mechanism:

  • \(X=\) contract balance of asset \(A\)
  • \(Y=\) contract balance of asset \(B\)
  • \(k=\) invariance factor
  • key relation \(k=X\times\ Y\)

Prices

  • when you want to sell \(x\le X\) you receive \(y\) that maintains invariance. 
  • implied exchange rate: \(e=\frac{x}{y}\)
  • maintain constant product post trade: \[k=(X+x)(Y-y)~ \Leftrightarrow~y=\frac{xY}{X+x}.\]

Economist's view:

  • ad hoc price rule
  • \(\to\) fundamental question: is this adequate/fair risk compensation for liquidity providers?
  • this paper:
    1. under what conditions will LPs participate
    2. how does this compare to a limit order book
    3. what stylized facts on willingness to provide liquidity can we see in the data

How do you organize DEX trading? EXAMPLE

automated market maker

invariant \(k=4\times4=16\) 

Instantaneous exchange rate:

1             =   1

Contract deposit:

How do you organize DEX trading? EXAMPLE

automated market maker

sell 4 DAI for USDC

what price will therefore be quoted?

\begin{array}{rcl} k&=&\#\text{DAI}\times\#\text{USDC}\\ 16&=&(4+4)\times(4-y)\\ x&=&2 \end{array}

how many USDC?

e=x/y~~\to~~e=2

How do you organize DEX trading? EXAMPLE

automated market maker

Problem: large "slippage" (or price impact)

  • imagine: deposit is 100 DAI & USDC:
    • \(k=100\times100=10,000~\to\) for \(x=4\) need \(y=100-10000/104=3.85\)
       
  • imagine: deposit is 10,000 DAI & USDC:
    • \(k=10,000\times10,000=100,000,000~\to\) for \(x=4\) need \(y=10,000-100,000,000/10,004=3.998\)
       
  • ​\(\to\) the more money is in the contracts, the lower the price impact

How do you organize DEX trading? other mechanisms

automated market maker

  • anyone can become a liquidity provider when supplying both sides of a pair
     
  • trades carry a fee of 30bps \(\to\) paid to liquidity providers (pooled)
     
  • LPs still face opportunity costs relative to all other assets \(\to\) income must be sufficient

supercool feature

automated market maker

  • establish and sell a new token
     

    • create token
    • deposit token and counterasset (e.g., DAI)
    • \(\to\) opening price
    • \(\to\) new purchases will increase price

  •  

Dark side of DEx trading: Miner extractable value

Mempool \(\Rightarrow\) Front-Running!

So what's the Problem?

a

b

c

d

e

f

g

However: although front-running is annoying, it is only a concern if it is intrinsically profitable.

My paper:

  • current pricing mechanisms in swap DEXes fundamentally allow arbitrage
  • pricing based on a canonical microstructure model does not
  • \(\to\) there is a way shut down MEV at the source

Problem: MEMPOOL Frontrunning is intrinsically profitable

\(X\)

\(Y\)

normal trade: sell \(x\) \(\to\) get \(y'\)

\(Y-y'\)

\(X+x\)

front-running:

  1. front-runner: sells \(x\) \(\to\) gets \(y'\)
  2. front-run: sells \(x\) \(\to\) gets \(y''\)
  3. front-runner: buys \(x\) \(\to\) pays \(y''\) 

\(Y-y'-y''\)

\(X+2x\)

\(y'>y''~\Rightarrow\)

front-running is intrinsically profitable

Disclaimer:

  • this problem is well-known
  • fees can mitigate it
  • several protocols such as the latest iteration by Balancer try to combat it

Problem: MEMPOOL Frontrunning is intrinsically profitable

\(X\)

\(Y\)

\(Y-y'\)

\(X+x\)

\(Y-y'-y''\)

\(X+2x\)

\(y'=y''~\Rightarrow\)

front-running is not intrinsically profitable

What would be desirable?

Hard-Coded Market Making

  1. Time consistent: cannot profitably split orders over time.
     
  2. Front-running is not intrinsically profitable. 
     
  3. Liquidity splitting invariance
     
  4. No Multi-venue arbitrage/ping-pong trading

   

CPAMM

canonical

How do you organize DEX trading?

Atomic swaps

How do you organize DEX trading?

Liquidity?

  • Laissez-faire: Etherdelta or Kyber
    • people submit contracts (limit orders) on-chain
    • system collects info
    • system offers "tools" to trade against standing contracts
  • Hybrid: 0x
    • "dark liquidity"
    • off-chain/sidechain purchase/sale agreements
    • system matches compatible orders and posts on-chain
  • Automated market maker (AMM) (Uniswap)
    • AMM holds assets on both sides
    • offers two-sided quotes (\(\to\) always liquid)
    • prices adjust continuously to demand/supply shifts

How do you organize DEX trading?

automated market maker

Price mechanism:

  • risk-neutral "invariance" pricing
  • at price, contract (AMM) is indifferent between buying and selling
  • \(X=\) contract balance of asset \(A\)
  • \(Y=\) contract balance of asset \(B\)
  • \(k=\) invariance factor
  • key relation \(k=X\times\ Y\)

Prices

  • when you want to sell \(x\le X\) you receive \(y\) that maintains invariance. 
  • implied exchange rate: \(e=\frac{x}{y}\)

superannoying feature

automated market maker

  • front-running

    • transactions enter mem-pool

    • \(\to\) all visible there

    • arbitrageur make instant-swap trade at higher gas price

      • \(\to\) trade instead of original trade

      • \(to\) reverse to gain slippage from earlier trader

Convenient feature for arbitrage: Flash loans (Flash swaps)

automated market maker

  • take three pairs (ignore that BTC is not directly on Ethereum)

    • BTC-DAI

    • ETH-BTC

    • ETH-DAI

  • three pairs must satisfy non-arbitrage condition
  • e.g. if ETH:DAI =1:100 and BTC:DAI=1:10000 then BTC:ETH=1:100
  • say BTC:ETH=1:200 then
    • borrow (say) 10,000 DAI
    • use DAI to buy  1 BTC
    • sell 1 BTC for 200 ETH and
    • sell 200 ETH for 20000 DAI
    • of which you use 10,000 DAI to repay loan and pocket 10,000
  • Normally, this is hard!
  • But on blockchain you can do all operations in one go
  • \(\to\) no risk of leg of transaction not going through or non-delivery
  • flash (single-block) loans enable this

How does it look?

automated market maker

\(\to\) simply connect with MetaMask (or similar wallet)

Summary of workflow

Crypto

Exchange

Traditional

Internalizer

Wholeseller

Darkpool

Investor

Venue

Broker

Settlement

Investor

Venue

Settlement

On chain

Main differences

Trading in Equity vs Crypto

  • regulated environment
  • firm trading rules
  • listing requirements
  • multi-step process
  • complicated settlement
  • many intermediaries

Equity Market

Crypto Market

  • unregulated environment
  • no trading rules - manipulation must be assumed
  • single step process
  • use of intermediaries is a choice
  • crypto exchange are closer to brokerages than equity exchanges
  • settlement a choice and straightforward
  • fully decentralized trading is possible and most exciting innovation

Some data

based on Khapko, Malinova, Park, and Zoican (2018)

Some data

Some data

Some data

Distribution of changes in beneficiary ownership

most tokens stay at exchanges and don't get settled on the blockchain

some usage tokens are "in use"

Transactions costs

Source: Interactive Brokers

Broker
Level

crypto exchange fees for $1,000,000 market order

account

wire/in-out

  • 25 bps = 2,500 trading fee

  • in/out fee 0.1% - 3%

  • mining fee ($0.25)

$1,000,000 market order

  • on April 30, 2019: Tether does not have cash reserves equal to 100% of the outstanding Tethers.
  • May 15, 2019 court hearing: Tether did invest in instruments beyond cash, including Bitcoin

Historically: “Tether Platform currencies are 100% backed by actual fiat currency
assets in our reserve account.”

Text

Today: "The Tether Platform is fully reserved when the sum of all tethers in circulation is less than or equal to the value of our reserves."

IS BITCOIN REALLY UN-TETHERED?
JOHN M. GRIFFIN and AMIN SHAMS
Journal of Finance 2020

vs.

Why does that matter?

  • Tether = ‘pushed’
    • print an unbacked digital dollar to purchase Bitcoin.
    • \(\to\) additional supply of Tether creates unwarranted inflation in Bitcoin price

Text

IS BITCOIN REALLY UN-TETHERED?
JOHN M. GRIFFIN and AMIN SHAMS
Journal of Finance 2020

vs.

  • Tether = ‘pulled’
    • driven by legitimate demand from investors who use Tether as a medium of exchange
    • \(\to\) the price impact of Tether reflects natural market demand

Text

IS BITCOIN REALLY UN-TETHERED?
JOHN M. GRIFFIN and AMIN SHAMS
Journal of Finance 2020

Flow of events

  • Tether is authorized
  • moved to Bitfinex 
  • then slowly distributed to other Tether-based exchanges (Poloniex and Bittrex)
  • \(\to\) almost no Tether returns to the Tether issuer to be redeemed
  • Kraken (major exchange for Tether\(\to\) USD) accounts for only a small proportion of transactions

Figure 1. Aggregate Flow of Tether between Major Addresses

Figure 3. Aggregate Flow of Bitcoin between Major Addresses.

Top Accounts Associated with the Flow of Tether from and Bitcoin to Bitfinex

  • three main Tether exchanges, Bitfinex, Poloniex, and Bittrex, have considerable cross-exchange Bitcoin flows
  • cross-exchange Bitcoin flows on Bitcoin closely match Tether flows
  • one large player has >50% of the exchange of Tether for
  • Bitcoin at Bitfinex
  • \(\to\) distribution of Tether into market from ONE large player and not many different investors 

If Tether is printed independently
of demand and pushed onto the market then ...

  • \(\nearrow\) money supply in crypto
  • \(\nearrow\) cryptocurrency prices through artificial demand 
  • if traded strategically, Tether can further impact and manipulate Bitcoin prices

the 1% of hours with the strongest lagged Tether flow are associated with 58.8% of the Bitcoin buy-and-hold return over the period.

Is the Price Effect Economically Important?

the "normal-times" returns

Sex, drugs, and bitcoin: How much illegal activity is financed through cryptocurrencies?
Foley, Karlsen, Putniņš, 2019, Review of Financial Studies

  • 25% of bitcoin users are involved in illegal activity.
  • 76 billion of illegal activity per year involves bitcoin (46% of bitcoin transactions)
  • close in scale to US and European markets for illegal drugs
  • illegal share of bitcoin activity \(\searrow\) with mainstream interest in bitcoin
  • cryptocurrencies are transforming the black markets by enabling “black e-commerce”

Cryptocurrency Pump-and-Dump Schemes
Tao Li, Donghwa Shin, and Baolian Wang, 2020

What is pump and dump?

arranged via Telegram Channels

  • prices of pumped cryptocurrencies begin rising five minutes before a P&D starts.
  • some pump group organizers offer premium memberships to allow certain investors to receive pump signals before others do (\(\to\) insiders)
  • Average P&D insiders make one Bitcoin (about $10,000) in profit
  • only investors who buy in the first 20
    seconds after a P&D begins make a profit

Other Tidbits of Information

  • P&D= price manipulation that involves artificially inflating an asset price before selling the cheaply purchased assets at a higher price.
  • Such schemes are most common with microcap stocks and have recently become popular in the cryptocurrency market (Shifflet and Vigna, 2018).
  • U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC): P&D is illegal in the stock market
  • Regulation of P&Ds in the cryptocurrency market is weak or nonexistent.

Market Design with Blockchain Technology

Katya Malinova and Andreas Park

What is different?

1. Multiple trading protocols are possible

User-facing exchange mask

Fully Decentralized, "OTC",

Peer-to-Peer Exchange

What is different?

2. High Level of Transparency

See transactions between "addresses" (="IDs")

What is different?

3. You can tell who owns what

To sum up: What is different?

  1. Exchange-trading and Peer to Peer is possible
    • current world peer-to-peer -- through intermediaries
      • a dealer/market maker is on one side of trade
      • parties know who they are trading with
    • technology enables frictionless value transfer
  2. Past transactions are visible
    • may be able to see frequent "traders"
  3. Current holdings are visible
    • may be able to tell who the "whales" are

=> Informational environment changes drastically

 Key: wallets/addresses = IDs  but NOT = traders

Research Question

How does the design of ledger transparency and identifier-usage with possible P2P interactions affect trading behavior and economic outcomes?

  • possible ledger transparency regimes:
    • visible to all
    • hidden (from some)
  • possible identifier-usage regimes:
    • mandate single IDs per entity
    • allow multiple IDs
      • allows to obfuscate holdings (Buterin 2015)

Who benefits and loses under which regime?

Literature

  1. Economics of blockchain protocols and transaction costs
    • there is a large literature in computer science, e.g., Eyal and Sirer (2014)
    • Gans and Halaburda (2015); and Halaburda and Gandel (2016)
    • Budish (2018), Saleh (2017), Biais, Bidiere, Bouvard, Casamatta (2018)
    • Huberman, Leshno, and Moallemi (2017), Easley, O'Hara, Basu (2018)
  2. Smart contracts and other uses of blockchain
    • Cong and He [2017], Yermark (2017)
  3. Blockchain and financial securities/markets
    • Boehm et al [2015]; Harvey [2016], Raskin and Yermack [2016; 2017]; Aune, Krellenstein, O’Hara, and Slama [2017]

Model Ingredients

  • Risky asset, normally distributed 
  • Two large investors
    • Each period one is hit with size Q=1 liquidity shock.

    • Other can absorb the shock at zero cost.

  • ​Continuum of 1/    small investors
    • ​trade with probability       at "public" price
    • each period, mass 1 wants to buy, mass 1 wants to sell
  • Infinitely many trading periods
N(0,\sigma^2)
\rho\le1/2
\rho

Disclaimer:

  • no asymmetric information 
  • => our results need not be applicable to all asset classes
\rho

Model Ingredients:
Trading and Timing

 

  • When hit with a shock, the "liquidity trader" (LT) may:
    • trade peer-to-peer (OTC)  (with small and/or large peers)
      • other large: "liquidity provider" (LP)
    • trade with a risk-averse intermediary at

       
      • Intermediary's inventory I "shifts" the public price
    • net-trades with intermediary = inefficient transfer of risk 
  • Unfilled positions clear with intermediary at end of stage game.
p(q)=\frac{\kappa \sigma^2}{N}\ (-I+q) \equiv \frac{\ell}{2} (q-I)

Model Ingredients: Costs

  • Data processing/complexity to contact q
  • Quadratic cost to contact mass q of IDs:
    • cost c is a loss to aggregate welfare
    • pay        and trade quantity
  • Linear mining/validation cost:
    • pay       to trade with     IDs
\rho q
\frac{c}{2} q^2
\gamma q
q

Direct

  • LT to LP: Buy quantity Q at price p?
    1. LP buys Q from intermediary and moves the "public price" P to​
       
    2. LP to LT: "sell you Q at price ≫ p?"
  • Front-runner pays validation costs.
P+ \ell/2 \times Q

Idea:

  • keep "risk" of transparency within trading model
  • for investors, can think of other costs, e.g., stealing of investment strategies

Indirect

Model Ingredients: Transparency of Ownership

  1. Full transparency = common knowledge of who is large
    • assume single ID (since validation costs increase in # of IDs)
  2. No transparency
    • only single ID allowed
  3. No transparency (ownership cannot be inferred)
    • continuum of IDs (to obfuscate ownership)

Requires a system design choice:

  • allow an entity (individual, investment fund) only a single ID per instrument
  • possible with private blockchain

Benchmark:
fully transparent (single ID) ownership

Options for Large Trader

Trade with small investors and intermediary

Trade with large investor
 

  • costs:
    • complexity + validation
    • intermediation
  • costs
    • reveal info about the trading needs
    • => [model choice]:
      LT may get “front-run” by LP.

​​

Repeated setting:

Front-running is punished by “grim trigger” & trade forever with small and intermediary.

Single shot:
LP always extracts all surplus (or would front-run).

The Benchmark Equilibrium

  1. In a repeated game, "social norms" have bite and front-running can always be avoided.
  2. LT always trades with LP.
  3. LT and LP share the cost savings.
  4. Price concession
    • For small discount factor (infrequent interaction) price concession is necessary.
    • For large enough discount factors (≈ frequent interactions), price concession = 0 is an equilibrium.

Opaque single ID ownership

Equilibrium

  • The optimal mass of IDs to contact is independent of the intermediary's inventories/public price.
  • Mass x* depends on:
    •   : probability of small traders accepting the offer
    •   : the (il-)liquidity of the intermediated market
    •   : complexity/data processing costs.
\rho
x^*=\max\{0, \frac{\ell \rho}{\ell \rho^2+c} - \frac{\rho\gamma}{\ell \rho^2+c}\}
\ell
c
  • When the  validation cost is not too large,              , the liquidity trader trades with both continuum & intermediaries
\gamma < \ell

Opaque multi-ID ownership

Closest and native to "public" blockchains:

  • anyone can participate anonymously
  • can create as many accounts as I want
  • described by Ethereum founder as simple solution to achieve privacy
  • private blockchains can choose to organize like this

Acceptance Probabilities in Opaque Settings

small traders

large trader

small traders

large trader

small traders

large trader

filled

unfilled


Opaque Single ID

Opaque Multi-ID: LP accepts

Opaque Multi-ID: LP rejects

\rho
\frac{2\rho}{1+\rho}>\rho
\frac{\rho}{1+\rho}<\rho

Decision problem LT

accept offer

"target" small investors only

  • (small) price concession to entice the large trader (but also paid to and "wasted on" small traders)
  • larger amount => complexity costs
  • no price concession
  • smaller amount
  • => expensive interaction with intermediary
  • => smaller complexity cost

Decision problem LP

"target" IDs of both: large and small

front run

  • incurs validation fees when front-running

Equilibrium & More

Result 1: There exists an equilibrium with no front-running where

  • LP accepts
  • price concession = 0

provided

  • the discount factor is large enough
    • = frequent interactions.
  • or the intermediated market is sufficiently liquid
    • = front running not very profitable (small quantity and low price advantage)
  • or validation costs are sufficiently high
    • = sunk cost for front-running too high.

Equilibrium & More

Result 2 (numerical): For small discount (=infrequent interaction) factors, the equilibrium with no front-running where LP accept does not exist. Then:

  • In equilibrium, LT offers p = 0 to the continuum, and
  • LP's IDs reject the offer.
     

=> "over-trading" with intermediary

  • Observation: an increase in the validation cost may curb front-running.

 

 

Comparing the designs

Observations

 

  • Trades with intermediary => socially inefficient 
    • better if large traders interact
    • otherwise: intermediary faces imbalance 
  • Small with large traders => complexity costs
  • By construction, payoffs under the full transparency benchmark are highest.
  • The trade-off for opaque regimes are:
    • complexity cost vs
    • intermediation cost

Comparing multi- vs single-ID opaque designs

 

  • Finding 1:
    • When large traders do not trade with each other, the welfare is the same in both opaque systems, irrespective of the ID-ownership setup.
  • Finding 2:
    • When large do trade with one another with multi-ID ownership, the welfare in this setting is higher than in the single-ID setting.

Payoffs to Large Traders

Finding 3:

For the average equilibrium stage payoffs of large traders.

  1. In multi-ID, when large traders do not interact, eq. payoffs lower than in opaque single-ID.
  2. In multi-ID, when large traders interact and p=0, eq.  payoffs larger than in opaque single-ID.
     

Finding 4: (Numerical)

There exist parametric configurations such that large traders trade with each other at p > 0 in the multi-ID ownership setting, but their average equilibrium payoff in the opaque single-ID setting is higher.

 

Summary

  1. "Back office" settlement has important front office implications!
    • with peer-to-peer there are critical design choices
      • Who can see the ledger?
      • How are virtual identities managed?
  2. Findings:
    • Transparent ledger with single IDs is welfare optimal and has lowest wealth redistribution (almost by construction)
    • Between (A) public blockchain solution with multiple IDs and (B) private, non-transparent ledger with single IDs:
      • public blockchain privacy solution has higher aggregate welfare
      • but does not necessarily lead to higher payoffs for large investors.

MFRM: Trading of Crypto Assets - Part 2

By Andreas Park

MFRM: Trading of Crypto Assets - Part 2

  • 854